구글와이드(336x280)_상단 2개


Tulip mania (개인)자료용 글들

Tulip mania

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

Jump to: navigation, search

Contents

[hide]
Pamphlet from the Dutch tulipomania, printed in 1637
Enlarge
Pamphlet from the Dutch tulipomania, printed in 1637
Anonymous 17th-century watercolor of the Semper Augustus, the most famous bulb, which sold for a record price.
Enlarge
Anonymous 17th-century watercolor of the Semper Augustus, the most famous bulb, which sold for a record price.
The term tulip mania (alternatively tulipomania) is used metaphorically to refer to any large economic bubble. The term originally came from the period in the history of the Netherlands during which demand for tulip bulbs reached such a peak that enormous prices were charged for a single bulb. It took place in the first part of the 17th century, especially in 1636-37.
The event is remembered in part because of its extended discussion in the book Extraordinary Popular Delusions and the Madness of Crowds, written by popular British journalist Charles Mackay in 1843, more than two centuries after the event. Mackay omitted mentioning that during 1636-37, the Netherlands suffered from an epidemic of bubonic plague, and severe setbacks in the Thirty Years War. [1]. Modern scholars (e.g. Garber) consider the event much less extraordinary than did Mackay. Indeed, the belief in the existence of a Dutch tulip mania may itself be an extraordinary popular delusion.

[edit] History

The tulip, introduced to Europe in the middle of the 16th century from Ottoman Turkey, experienced a strong growth in popularity in the United Provinces (now the Netherlands), boosted by competition between members of the upper classes for possession of the rarest tulips. Competition escalated until prices reached very high levels.
Tulip cultivation in the United Provinces is thought to have started in 1593, when Charles de L'Ecluse first bred tulips able to tolerate the harsher conditions of the Low Countries from bulbs sent to him from Turkey by Ogier de Busbecq. The flower rapidly became a coveted luxury item and a status symbol. Special breeds were given exotic names or named after Dutch naval admirals. The most spectacular and highly sought-after tulips had vivid colors, lines, and flames on the petals as a result of being infected with a tulip-specific virus known as the Tulip Breaking potyvirus.

[edit] Popular view

In 1623, a single bulb of a famous tulip variety could cost as much as a thousand Dutch florins (the average yearly income at the time was 150 florins). Tulips were also exchanged for land, valuable livestock, and houses. Allegedly, a good trader could earn sixty thousand florins a month.
By 1635, a sale of 40 bulbs for 100,000 florins was recorded. By way of comparison, a ton of butter cost around 100 florins and "eight fat swine" 240 florins. A record was the sale of the most famous bulb, the Semper Augustus, for 6,000 florins in Haarlem.
By 1636, tulips were traded on the stock exchanges of numerous Dutch towns and cities. This encouraged trading in tulips by all members of society, with many people selling or trading their other possessions in order to speculate in the tulip market. Some speculators made large profits as a result.
Some traders sold tulip bulbs that had only just been planted or those they intended to plant (in effect, tulip futures contracts). This phenomenon was dubbed windhandel, or "wind trade", and took place mostly in the taverns of small towns using an arcane slate system to indicate bid prices. A state edict from 1610 (well before the alleged bubble) made that trade illegal by refusing to enforce the contracts, but the legislation failed to curtail the activity.
In February 1637 tulip traders could no longer get inflated prices for their bulbs, and they began to sell. The bubble burst. People began to suspect that the demand for tulips could not last, and as this spread a panic developed. Some were left holding contracts to purchase tulips at prices now ten times greater than those on the open market, while others found themselves in possession of bulbs now worth a fraction of the price they had paid. Allegedly, thousands of Dutch, including businessmen and dignitaries, were financially ruined.
Attempts were made to resolve the situation to the satisfaction of all parties, but these were unsuccessful. Ultimately, individuals were stuck with the bulbs they held at the end of the crash—no court would enforce payment of a contract, since judges regarded the debts as contracted through gambling, and thus not enforceable in law.
Lesser versions of the tulipomania also occurred in other parts of Europe, although matters never reached the state they had in the Netherlands. In England in 1800, it was common to pay fifteen guineas for a single tulip bulb. This sum would have kept a labourer and his family in food, clothes and lodging for six months.

[edit] Competing views

Mike Dash, author of the modern popular history "Tulipomania," states
The history of the tulip mania itself, however, remains remarkably obscure, and even now it has never been the subject of an exhaustive scholarly inquiry.
....My general feeling, after reviewing the available material, is that even after sounding the necessary notes of caution about the reliabilty of the popular accounts, historians and particularly economists remain guilty of exaggerating the real importance and extent of the tulip mania. (p.222, footnote)
A 2002 paper by UCLA's Earl A. Thompson and Jonathan Treussard, "The Tulipmania: Fact or Artifact?", provides an alternate explanation for Dutch tulip mania: that it was not caused by irrational speculation, but rather by a Dutch parliamentry decree (originally sponsored by Dutch investors made skittish by the Thirty Years' War then in progress) that made the purchase of tulip-bulb "futures contracts" a nearly risk-free proposition:
...both the famous popular discussion of Mackay and the famous academic discussion of Posthumus, 1929, point out a highly peculiar part of this episode. In particular, they tell us that, on February 24, 1637, the self-regulating guild of Dutch florists, in a decision that was later ratified by the Dutch Parliament, announced that all futures contracts written after November 30, 1636 and before the re-opening of the cash market in the early Spring, were to be to [sic] interpreted as option contracts. They did this by simply relieving the futures buyers of the obligation to buy the future tulips, forcing them merely to compensate the sellers with a small fixed percentage of the contract price.
Given data about the specific payoffs present in the futures and option contracts, the authors determine that tulip bulb prices in fact hewed closely to what a rational economic model would dictate: "tulip contract prices before, during, and after the 'tulipmania' appear to provide a remarkable illustration of market efficiency."

[edit] See also

Other bubbles

[edit] Further reading

Wikisource has original text related to this article:

[edit] External links

==============================================

THE TULIPOMANIA

An Investing Bubble

What madness this was! - Lucan.
Tulips were first grown in Western Europe in the middle of the sixteenth century. They were cultivated by Counsellor Herwart of Augsburg, a man famous for his collection of rare exotic plants. The bulbs were sent to Herwart by a friend from Constantinople, where the tulip had already been popular for a long time. (The word "tulip" is believed to originate from a Turkish word for turban.) In 1559 tulips were seen in Herwart's garden by Conrad Gesner who, in the following ten years, claims to have popularised them in Europe.
Tulips became sought after by the wealthy, especially in Holland and Germany - wealthy people in Amsterdam sent directly to Constantinople for bulbs, paying high prices for them. Bulbs arrived in England from Vienna in 1600.
The tulip's reputation grew to such heights that, by 1634, wealthy people who did not have a tulip collection were judged to have bad taste. Many learned men, including Pompeius de Angelis and the celebrated Lipsius of Leyden, the author of the treatise "De Constantia," were passionately fond of tulips.
An overwhelming desire to own tulips gripped the middle classes. Merchants and shopkeepers, even those with modest incomes, began to vie with each other for tulips - and in the preposterous prices they paid for them. A trader from Harlaem paid half of his life savings for a single bulb. He didn't buy for profit; he just wanted his friends to admire it.
The popularity of the tulip in Holland is inexplicable. The Dutch are generally prudent people, yet tulips are inferior to roses in both beauty and perfume. Even sweet-peas are prettier than tulips, while both sweet-peas and roses flower for longer than tulips.
Cowley, however, was loud in praise of the tulip. He said,
The tulip next appeared, all over gay,
But wanton, full of pride, and full of play;
The world can't show a dye but here has place;
Nay, by new mixtures, she can change her face;
Purple and gold are both beneath her care-
The richest needlework she loves to wear;
Her only study is to please the eye,
And to outshine the rest in finery.
This, though not very good poetry, was the description by a poet.
In History of Inventions, Beckmann paints a truer picture than Cowley, in prose more pleasing than Cowley's poetry:
There are few plants that acquire, through accident, weakness, or disease, so many variegations as the tulip. When uncultivated, and in its natural state, it is almost of one colour, has large leaves, and an extraordinarily long stem. When it has been weakened by cultivation, it becomes more agreeable in the eyes of the florist. The petals are then paler, smaller, and more diversified in hue; and the leaves acquire a softer green colour. Thus this masterpiece of culture, the more beautiful it turns, grows so much the weaker, so that, with the greatest skill and most careful attention, it can scarcely be transplanted, or even kept alive.
A mother often loves her sick and ever-ailing child better than her more healthy offspring. The same principle may account for the unmerited praise lavished upon these fragile blossoms.
In 1634, the madness among the Dutch to own tulips became so great that day-to-day work was neglected. Even the lowest members of society took up the tulip trade.
As the mania increased, prices rose, until, in 1635, a large number of people were investing fortunes of 100,000 florins to own forty tulip bulbs. It then became necessary to sell tulips by their weight in perits. (A perit was a small weight - less than a grain. 480 grains equalled 1 ounce.)
Prices for different varieties were as follows:
  • Admiral Liefken, weighing 400 perits = 4,400 florins
  • Admiral Von der Eyk, weighing 446 perits = 1,260 florins
  • Shilder of 106 perits = 1,615 florins
  • Viceroy of 400 perits = 3,000 florins
  • Semper Augustus, weighing 200 perits = 5,500 florins
The Semper Augustus was much sought after, and even an inferior bulb could cost 2000 florins. In early 1636 there were only two of these in Holland and these were not of the best quality. One was held by dealer in Amsterdam, and the other in Harlaem. A speculator offered twelve acres of building ground for the Harlaem tulip. The Amsterdam tulip sold for 4600 florins, a new carriage, two grey horses, and a complete suit of harness.
An industrious author of the time, Munting, who wrote one thousand pages about the tulipomania, recorded the following items - and their value - which were traded for a single Viceroy bulb:

Item Value
(florins)
Two lasts of wheat 448
Four lasts of rye 558
Four fat oxen 480
Eight fat swine 240
Twelve fat sheep 120
Two hogsheads of wine 70
Four casks of beer 32
Two tons of butter 192
A complete bed 100
A suit of clothes 80
A silver drinking cup 60
Total 2,500


Anyone returning to Holland who had missed the beginning of the mania was capable of grave error.
In Blainville's Travels the story is told of a wealthy merchant who received a valuable consignment of tulips from the Middle East. A sailor brought the news to the merchant in his warehouse that his tulip bulbs had arrived. The sailor, who enjoyed onions, saw what he mistook for an onion lying on a table amongst the merchant's silks and velvets and slipped it into his pocket, to accompany the fish he was going to have for breakfast. He escaped with his prize, and returned to the quay to eat his breakfast. He had barely gone when the merchant missed his Semper Augustus, worth three thousand florins, or about 280 pounds sterling. The merchant turned his warehouse upside down searching for the bulb until someone remembered the sailor.
The unhappy merchant and his followers rushed to the key where they found the sailor sitting quietly on a coil of ropes, eating the last morsel of his "onion". Little did the sailor know his whole ship's crew could have been fed for 12 months for the price of his breakfast. The sailor was jailed for several months for his trouble.
Another story is told of an English traveller, an amateur botanist, who happened to see a tulip-bulb lying in the conservatory of a wealthy Dutchman. Unaware of its value, he took out his penknife and peeled off its coats, with the view experimenting on it. He then began cutting it into pieces. Suddenly the owner pounced on; with fury in his eyes he asked the traveller if he knew what he had been doing?
"Peeling a most extraordinary onion," replied the philosopher.
"Hundert tausend duyvel," said the Dutchman; "It's an Admiral Von der Eyk!"
"Thank you," replied the traveller, taking out his note-book to record the variety; "are these admirals common in your country?"
"Death and the devil," said the Dutchman, seizing the astonished man of science by the collar; "come before the magistrate, and you shall see."
Despite his protests, the traveller was led through the streets, followed by a mob. When brought before the magistrate, he learned that the bulb he had cut up was worth four thousand florins.
Although he pleaded extenuating circumstances, the traveller was imprisoned until he could pay for the damage.
The demand for rare tulips increased so much in 1636, that they were traded on Amsterdam's Stock Exchange and in Rotterdam, Harlaem, Leyden, Alkmar, Hoorn, and other towns. For the first time, symptoms of gambling became apparent too. Stockbrokers, ever alert for a new speculation, dealt largely in tulips. They used every trick in the book to produce price fluctuations.
At first, as with all gambling mania, confidence was high - everybody gained. The tulip-brokers speculated in the rise and fall of tulip stocks. They made large profits, buying when prices fell, and selling when they rose.
Many individuals suddenly grew rich. People now rushed to trade in tulips, like flies around a honeypot. Everyone imagined that the passion for tulips would last for ever. They believed that wealthy people from all over the world would send to Holland, and pay whatever prices were asked for tulips. They dreamt that the riches of Europe would be concentrated on the shores of the Zuyder Zee, and poverty would be banished from Holland.
Noblemen, citizens, farmers, mechanics, seamen, footmen, maidservants, even chimney-sweeps and old clotheswomen, dabbled in tulips. People converted their property into cash, and invested it in flowers. Houses and lands were offered for sale at ruinously low prices, or used to pay for tulips.
The frenzy spread beyond Holland's borders and money poured into Holland from all directions. Inflation then reared its ugly head and the prices of life's necessities rose strongly. Houses and lands, horses and carriages, and luxuries of every sort, rose in value.
The tulip trade became so wide spread and detailed that new laws were enacted for the guidance of the dealers. Officials were appointed who devoted themselves exclusively to the tulip trade.
In the smaller towns, where there was no official tulip exchange, the principal tavern was usually selected as the "showplace," where high and low traded in tulips, and confirmed their bargains over sumptuous entertainments. These dinners were sometimes attended by two or three hundred people, and large vases of tulips, in full bloom, were placed at regular intervals upon the tables and sideboards.
At last, however, wiser heads began to see that this folly could not last for ever. Rich people no longer bought the flowers for their gardens, but to sell them again at profit. It was realised that somebody must lose badly in the end. As this concern spread, prices fell, never to rise again.
Confidence was now destroyed. Dealers were gripped by universal panic and began defaulting on contracts. For example:
  • Dealer A had agreed to purchase ten Sempers Augustines from dealer B.
  • The agreed price was at four thousand florins each.
  • The delivery time was six weeks after the signing of the contract.
  • B was ready with the flowers at the appointed time.
  • But the price had fallen from four thousand florins to just three or four hundred florins,
  • Dealer A refused either to pay the difference or receive the tulips.
Defaulters were announced day after day in all the towns of Holland.
Hundreds of people who had begun to believe poverty would be banished from the land, suddenly found they were owners of bulbs worth only a small fraction of what they had paid for them.
The cries of distress resounded everywhere, and each man accused his neighbour. The few who had enriched themselves by selling their bulbs when the market was at its height hid their wealth or invested it in the English or other markets. Many who, for a brief season, had emerged from the humbler walks of life, were cast back into their original obscurity. Noble families were ruined and large merchants were reduced almost to the level of beggars.
Tulip-holders held public meetings hoping to find the best way forward. Deputies were sent to the government in Amsterdam, seeking a solution. At first, the government refused to interfere. It advised the tulip-holders to agree a plan among themselves.
Several meetings were held for this purpose, all of which were stormy.
After a lot of bickering and ill-will, it was agreed, in Amsterdam, that all contracts made in the height of the mania, or prior to the month of November 1636, would be null and void. For contracts made after that date, buyers would be freed from their contracts on payment of ten percent of the contract value to the seller.
Unfortunately, this decision gave no satisfaction. The sellers, who had tulips they had arranged to sell at high prices were naturally discontented. Those who had made contracts to buy were also unhappy at even having to pay ten percent of the contract price because tulips that had been worth six thousand florins, were now worth five hundred florins. Actions for breach of contract were threatened in all the courts of the country; but the courts refused to act on what they regarded as gambling transactions.
The matter was finally referred to the Provincial Council at the Hague. The council deliberated for three months before announcing that they could offer no final decision until they had more information. They advised that, in the mean time, every seller should, in the presence of witnesses, offer the tulips to the purchaser for previously agreed contract price. If the buyer refused to take them, they might be put up for sale by public auction, and the original buyer held responsible for the difference between the actual and the stipulated price. This was exactly the same as the failed plan recommended by the deputies. There was no court in Holland that would enforce payment.
The question was raised in Amsterdam, but the judges unanimously refused to interfere, on the ground that debts contracted in gambling were not debts in law.
To find a remedy was beyond the power of the government. And so the matter ended.
Those who were unlucky enough to be left holding worthless tulip were left to bear their ruin as philosophically as they could. Those who had made profits were allowed to keep them. Dutch commerce had suffered a severe shock, from which it took years to recover.
The Dutch mania spread to some extent to England. In the year 1636 tulips were publicly sold on the London Stock Exchange, where brokers worked hard to push prices up to the levels seen in Amsterdam. In Paris brokers also strove to create tulipmania. In both cities, however, brokers enjoyed only partial success.
The mania ultimately brought the flowers into great favour, and amongst a certain class of people tulips have ever since been prized more highly than any other flowers.
The Dutch are still notorious for their partiality to tulips, and continue to pay higher prices for them than any other people. Just as rich Englishmen boast of their fine race-horses or their old pictures, wealthy Dutchman vaunt their tulips.
In England today, strange as it may appear, a tulip costs more than an oak. If a black tulip could be found, it would be worth more than a dozen acres of standing corn.
In Scotland at the end of the 1600s the highest price paid for a tulip was ten guineas. (According to the supplement to the third edition of the Encyclopedia Britannica.) From that time, their value appears to have fallen until the year 1769, when the two most valuable species in England were the Don Quevedo, worth two guineas, and the Valentinier, worth two and a half guineas. These prices appear to have been the minimum.
In the year 1800, a typical price was fifteen guineas for a single bulb.
In 1835, buyers had become so foolish that a bulb of the variety Miss Fanny Kemble was auctioned for seventy-five pounds in London. Even more astonishing was the price quoted for of a tulip owned by a gardener in the King's Road, Chelsea. In his catalogues, it was labelled at two hundred guineas!
So a flower that is less impressive than the rose - a small bunch of which might be purchase for a penny - was valued at a sum that could keep a hard-working labourer and his family in food, clothes, and lodging for six years!
If chickweed and groundsel ever come into fashion, the wealthy would, no doubt, vie with each other in adorning their gardens with them, and paying the most extravagant prices for them. In so doing, they would hardly be more foolish than the admirers of tulips. The common prices for these flowers at the present time vary from five to fifteen guineas, according to the rarity of the species.

© TheTulipomania.com
http://www.thetulipomania.com/

null



바보들의 영문법 카페(클릭!!)

오늘의 메모....

시사평론-정론직필 다음 카페
http://cafe.daum.net/sisa-1

바보들의 영문법 다음 카페
http://cafe.daum.net/babo-edu/

티스토리 내 블로그
http://earthly.tistory.com/

내 블로그에 있는 모든 글들과 자료에 대한 펌과 링크는 무제한 허용됩니다.
(단, 내 블로그에 덧글쓰기가 차단된 자들에게는 펌, 트랙백, 핑백 등이 일체 허용되지 않음.)

그리고 내 블로그 최근글 목록을 제목별로 보시려면....
바로 아래에 있는 이전글 목록의 최근달을 클릭하시면 됩니다.
그러면 제목을 보고 편하게 글을 골라 보실 수 있습니다.

그리고 내 블로그내 글을 검색하시려면 아래 검색버튼을 이용하시면 됩니다.


가가챗창

flag_Visitors

free counters